Airliner windows don't open.
But that's not what Romney is hope'n.
"Let's open them," calmly
Suggested Mitt Romney.
With a brain like that, how is he cope'n?
Seriously; How has it come to the point where the party of Abe Lincoln and Teddy Roosevelt offers, as its standard bearer, a man who cannot quite grasp why the windows on a pressurized airliner are not openable?
Saturday, September 29, 2012
Tuesday, September 25, 2012
Perils of Quantitative Easing
On
Sept 13, 2012, the Federal Reserve announced it would begin a third round of
“quantitative easing.” This
means they intend to expand the money supply again. The Fed intends to begin purchasing $40 billion worth
of mortgage backed securities per month, and continue to do so until
unemployment comes down to an acceptable level. And at some point, they may begin buying U.S. Treasury Bills
again. In the first round of
bond buying, begun in March 2009, the Fed bought 1.25 trillion dollars worth of
corporate assets. And then in
November of 2010, the Fed began buying U.S. Treasury Bills, pumping an
additional 600 billion dollars into the economy. Where does the Fed get the
money to make these purchases? In
effect, they just print it.
What
are they doing and why are they doing it?
The Federal Reserve, like any central bank system, is simply trying to
control the money supply, keeping the availability of dollars at a level which
they hope will bring unemployment down to an acceptably low level, while still
keeping inflation from rising to an unacceptably high level. These two things
are what central banks try to do, and in the U.S., Congress has given the Fed a
specific mandate to do both.
Do
I object to this action which the Fed is undertaking? No—the unemployment rate is way too high, and something has
to be done about it. If it could
be brought down to a normal level, then the increased tax collections and
reduced welfare expense would, in and of itself, nearly balance the
budget. But I’m disappointed that
we are using no tools other than monetary policy to do this, when a combination
of fiscal policy and monetary policy would work infinitely better. Fiscal policy could be used with
surgical precision if we had a Congress with the will to do it. But we don’t, so the whole task of
bringing down unemployment is left to poor Mr. Bernanke, who has little more in
his tool box besides the “sledge hammer” of monetary easing.
Before
I explain what my real objection is, let’s take a moment to briefly consider
just what monetary policy really is. If a central bank wishes to add cash to the economy,
they simply buy up “commercial paper,” that is, the kind of IOUs that banks and
large corporations give to other banks.
By buying corporate bonds for cash, they take these bonds out of
circulation and put more cash into circulation. That supposedly expands the
money supply. And if they wish to
shrink the money supply, they sell some of the commercial paper from the vast hoard
in their portfolio at any given time, and that takes money out of circulation.
But there is just one
problem. Switching cash for
corporate bonds may not change the money supply as much as you may think,
because such bonds are in themselves a form of money. Money is anything that can be used
to pay a debt. And if a bundle of
bonds are written on blue chip companies, and are offered at an appropriate
discount, most investment banks, in normal times, will accept them as cash. In fact, an interest-bearing note
from a credit worthy company is better than cash, because cash does not pay
interest. And in normal times, the
overwhelming majority of the money in circulation is corporate paper—not U.S.
currency.
Whenever
there is a panic—a stock market crash, a war, or whatever--the market freezes
up and banks temporarily stop accepting corporate paper for debt payment. They
demand cash. So then these assets
cease to be liquid—they stop being money. Of course, some of them, such as subprime real
estate, should never have been money in the first place. But when the crash of 2008 hit, banks
not only stopped accepting questionable mortgages, they didn’t want good ones
either.
So this produced a liquidity crisis, as
a lot of the money in circulation just stopped being money and stopped
circulating. About 3 trillion dollars worth of liquidity instantly ceased to
exist. But the instruments, the
bonds, mortgages, promissory notes, etc, still exist somewhere. And if the economy ever fully recovers,
banks will start trading them. And
all 3 trillion bucks worth will become part of the money supply. And that’s why I get a little nervous
about quantitative easing. Just
about the time that unemployment gets down to normal, all of the dollars that
Mr. Bernanke has added to the economy will have some unexpected company, as
this slug of commercial paper suddenly becomes liquid again.
At
that point, the Fed will try to shrink the money supply by selling off
commercial paper in exchange for cash.
As they trade bonds for cash, this removes cash from circulation, but it
might not really remove much money, because by then the bonds put back into
circulation will have become money again.
And every month, even more of this money will be created as every
corporation in the country begins issuing more corporate debt. And it isn’t just corporations
that do this. You and I can expand the money supply. Some years back, my brother took out a home improvement
loan, secured by a mortgage. Over
the time he paid it back, he ended up mailing interest and principle payments
to a different bank every month.
He originally borrowed it form a local bank, but that note was traded to
banks all over the country. He had,
in effect, increased the money supply.
I
would suggest that we don’t even have a general agreement as to what “money”
is. If a credit card company
informs you that you have an additional $10,000 line of credit, is that
money? Well, it would spend
the same as money—wouldn’t it? So
how much control does the Fed have over the money supply when every man Jack
can create the stuff?
So
far, monetary policy has not produced much result. The stimulus did produce results. It is the reason that
unemployment never got much above 10% rather than ballooning to 25%, as it did in
the Hoover administration. If we
had a million businesses that had no access to credit but had customers banging
on the door, then monetary policy might create a few jobs. But right now, American corporations
are sitting on 3 trillion bucks and they aren’t spending any of it. They do not need cash or credit—they
need customers. Business needs a
whole generation of young people to begin entering the middle class, and not a
generation of middle aged consumers falling out of it. Business needs the
unemployed to have jobs—jobs secure enough that the workers are not afraid to
spend what they earn—but even more important, business needs the underemployed
to earn more discretionary income.
The stimulus was large enough to keep
unemployment from becoming disastrously worse, but not large enough to really
cure it. And none of the
quantitative easing has cured it either. I suppose that if we were to dump
enough dollars on the market, we would eventually bid down the value of the Dollar
to where those who hold dollars would start panic buying, hoping to unload
dollars while dollars can still buy something. But this is a pretty dangerous
game. The main peril of relying on monetary policy alone, aside from the fact
that it doesn’t work, is that it’s a lot easier to throw those dollars out
there than to ever call them back.
Tuesday, September 18, 2012
Oil, Imperialism, and the Real Causes of WWI
This
post is the Cat’s rather long book review of A Century of War, by Wm.
Engdahl: Engdahl,
a German historian, makes a persuasive case that all wars of the Twentieth
Century were about oil. He
explains that the British and Americans have never been told the truth about
why WWI was fought. We are told
that it was all some kind of silly mistake. But the real struggle was over oil, and the military and
industrial dominance that flows from control of that oil. Although the fields of France and
Russia were where most of the killing took place, the real prize was the oil
fields of Iraq, and whether England or Germany would control those oil fields. Forget about the Red Baron—it was
Laurence of Arabia who grabbed the real estate that mattered.
But
to explain the conflicts of the 20th century, Engdahl needs to explain the economic
order of the 19th and how that order came into being. So he begins his narrative with The
Congress of Vienna, in 1814, at the end of the Napoleonic wars. The outcome of
this congress was that Britain got what she wanted—the right to dominate the
seas and with it, world trade. The concessions she granted to Austria were
actually self-serving, in that it divided Europe in such a way that no one
power would be large enough to rival Britain in trade or war.
FREE
TRADE-- THE ULTIMATE CAUSE OF WAR.
In
1815, Britain began moving toward a free trade strategy, with the adoption of
the gold standard. At that time,
British industry was far superior to anything in Europe. But to maximize that advantage, Britain
had to pry open foreign markets. So Britain talked Europe into free trade
agreements. The culmination of
this free trade strategy was the repeal of the Corn Laws in 1846. Most
people think that the repeal of the Corn Laws was a victory for workers at the
expense of landowners. Actually,
workers lost. Allowing duty-free
importation of grain lowered the price of bread, but welfare payments were
pegged to the price of bread, and so were most working class wages. When the price dropped to half, so did
income. Also, farm laborers forced
off the land had to compete for urban jobs, which depressed wages even
further. And that was the whole
idea—to make British industry competitive by depressing wages.
The
worst victims of the Corn Law repeal were the Irish tenant farmers. Irish farmers grew potatoes, but they
mainly grew wheat. They had used half the wheat crop to pay rent, and lived off
the other half, plus they had the potatoes. But when the grain price dropped to half, they had to use
the entire wheat crop to pay rent. So when the potato crop failed, they starved to death. During the worst year of the famine,
they had a bumper crop of wheat, which could easily have fed everyone in
Ireland. But it was all
confiscated by the landlords for rent, and millions were left to starve. Free
trade radically lowered the standard of living of every worker in England and
Ireland. But factory owners grew
rich, and so did bankers and shippers.
FREE
TRADE’S SHORT-LIVED ADVANTAGE
In
the mid-nineteenth-century, free trade worked very well for British factory
owners, bankers, and ship owners.
But it did not work well for British workers, nor did it work well for
the countries Britain was trading with.
By 1850, some countries had begun to notice that. So the German states had united into a
customs union, or “Zollverein,” and had begun to follow the protectionist
policies of Frederich List. The
Germans complained that the British free trade argument had always been a
fraud. In 1815, the British had
said, in effect, “We have the most efficient industry in the world, and we have
a free trade economy; so imitate us and you too will prosper.” But Britain hadn’t always been a leader in industry, and they
hadn’t always had free trade. As
late as 1690, they had trailed far behind Europe in every technology. Yet in
the 18th century, they caught up with Europe and surpassed them. But
they did so by creating the most absolutely protectionist economy in history.
During
this time, with imports severely restricted, local industries had a good
potential for profit, so it became profitable to invest capital in them. British wealth was eagerly invested and
re-invested in British industry, and innovation of every kind was fully financed. It was in this protectionist
environment the British industry surpassed Europe. Then, England did an about-face and abruptly opened her
markets, as a way of inducing Europe to open its markets, so as to gain maximum
leverage from the technological lead they had then gained. But by the 1850s,
Europeans had decided that they would gain nothing from this arrangement. Since
their own factories lagged far behind the British, they would be unable to
compete and would fall even further behind and eventually cease to exist. So the Europeans opted for the
protectionist strategies of Frederich List.
THE
FREE TRADE PARADOX.
There
was, from the beginning, a paradox to the British plan. It contained the seeds
of its own destruction. Through a
century of extreme protectionism, they had gained a tremendous technical
lead. But to make any use of this
lead, they needed open markets, and the open markets in themselves would
eventually erode that technical lead. You can’t induce other countries to open
their markets to you unless you open yours. But as soon as you do this, capital investment can flow to
other countries, rather than be invested locally. If some other country, i.e.
India, has wages even lower than Britain, then it will be more profitable to build
new factories in India, rather than in Britain. Even if a new British factory could manage to stay in
business, the wage cost would always be higher, so profit would be lower. There
would always be a strong disincentive to re-investing British profits in
Britain. And there would be little
interest in trying to have a better trained workforce as a way of remaining
competitive, since education would require tax expenditure, and taxes would cut
into profit. But as British
industry was stagnating and British workers were reduced to serfdom, banks
still made profit and no one in power saw any need to change anything.
A
BOOM IN EUROPE.
As
Britain headed downward, Germany was booming. Under the Zollverein, imports were restricted and capital
flows were tightly controlled. Any
outside investment in Germany required government permission, as did German
investment abroad. German
investment was directed toward improvement of German industries, and these
investments were profitable, due to a protected markets price for the products
of those industries.
German
consumers paid a high initial cost for this. They paid higher prices for
everything they bought, but only for one generation. As German industrial output doubled every decade, innovation
flourished, productivity increased, and wages rose sharply. The German plan
also called for heavy investment in education. The first push was for universal literacy, quickly achieved
through a nationwide system of tax-supported primary schools. They then built technical high schools
and polytechnical colleges. By the
end of the 19th century, Germany had the best trained work force in
the world. German agriculture had
also improved, so that as Germany became self-sufficient in food, their workers
were better fed than the English.
And German colleges were turning out scientists and engineers by
the tens of thousands—some of them world-class.
In
the 1870s, Britain went into a depression that lasted over 20 years. But Germany continued to boom. In 1850, when Germany began to shift
away from free trade, they produced only insignificant amounts of iron. By 1900 they passed Britain, and by
1910 their output was 50% higher than Britain, at 15 million tons. Between 1880
and 1900, their steel output rose over 1000%. The situation was the same for coal, textiles, electric
power, and especially for chemicals.
In fact, Germany practically invented the modern chemical industry, with
the huge Bayer and BASF plants leading the way. They also took the lead in
chemical research, inventing aniline dye, aspirin, and several plastics. And the German merchant fleet went from
half a million tons in 1870, to 13 million in 1909. (And, though Engdahl
doesn’t mention it, in 1903, Fritz Haber, a chemist at BASF, developed a
process for extracting nitrogen from the air. This discovery
alone radically altered the balance of power. Germany had poor soil that was never very productive
without added nitrates. Munitions
also require nitrates. The only available source had been bat guano from
Bolivia. This was very expensive, and Germany could never have afforded enough
for high output agriculture and high munitions production at the same time. Besides, the Bolivian shipments had to
get past the British Navy. So war
between Britain and Germany would not have been a possibility. But Haber changed all that.)
Besides falling behind in gross output, Britain was
also no longer the leader in technical innovation. When internal combustion engines began to replace steam, it
was the Germans who won the race to develop the first practical IC engine,
first with the Otto engine, and then with the Diesel. (Engdahl could also
have mentioned that in 1840, Britain was producing the finest steam engines on
earth. But by the 1880s, the American made Corliss Engine was so superior that
British manufacturers were paying American patent royalties for the privilege
of building it. )
While
all this was happening, British bankers just collected the money and
re-invested it everywhere except in England, and did nothing as their country
went to hell in a hand-basket.
That’s the paradox. The
only reason Britain had pressed for free trade was to take full advantage of
their technical lead. But in just over half a century, free trade itself had
evaporated that lead. By the end
of the century, British bankers had noticed what was happening in Germany, and
it scarred them. Privately, they agreed that something would have to be
done about Germany. Using
monopolistic trade practices, Britain nearly ran the whole world during the 19th
century. And they were still
firmly in charge at the end of that century. But by then the top leaders realized that British dominance
would not continue much longer if Britain continued to stagnate, while other
countries, particularly Germany, continued to advance. Yet they failed to see the problem as a
British failure, wrought by their own greed and short-sightedness. They saw it as “the German problem,”
and began looking for a way to “do something about Germany.”
THREE
PILLORS OF THE BRITISH EMPIRE
Engdahl
says the British Empire was based on three things: a monopoly of gold, a monopoly of shipping, and a monopoly
of certain raw materials. To
have these monopolies, you need gold, shipping, and raw materials for
yourself--but you also need a practical way to deny these things to all
potential competitors. And that’s
what the Boer War was about.
When
gold was discovered in the Transvaal, the British seized the area, not out of
greed for gold, but to keep any other country from having it. Nearly all of the
gold from the California Gold Rush was bought up by British banks to keep it
off the market. For shipping, you
need a large merchant marine. But to maintain a shipping monopoly, you
also need the world’s largest navy, so that you can deny shipping to any
competitor, should it suit your convenience to do so. And to maintain a monopoly on raw materials----is what the
empire was for. During the
Nineteenth Century, using these three monopolies, Britain was able to dominate
world trade and dominate the world
INFORMAL EMPIRE
INFORMAL EMPIRE
The
Boer War was very nasty and very expensive. So in the 1890s, the ruling class in England began talking
about an “informal empire”---where they would still dominate the world, but use
less military leverage, and more financial leverage. Don’t send in the Army--send in the bankers--and threaten to
cut off their credit. The informal
empire relied on a partnership between the British banks, the leaders in
Parliament, the leaders of key industries, the military, and the foreign
intelligence service, but with the bankers clearly in charge. These were separate entities, but in
dealing with foreign countries, they worked like five fingers of the same fist.
If a foreign company applied for a loan at a branch of a British bank, any
information disclosed to the loan officer would be immediately forwarded to a
foreign intelligence officer, unless the bank employee was a foreign
intelligence officer, which he might easily have been.
In many countries, if a local political
leader caused problems for a British bank, the British Army would be sent in.
And any time the British Army had problems gaining cooperation from political
leaders, the bankers would be sent in---to cut off credit and topple the
regime. Engdahl points out that this tactic, which the U.S. now uses through
the IMF, was learned from the British. The whole system was glued together by
control of information, gathered by the foreign intelligence service. And a pliant parliament passed whatever
laws were needed to make it work. Countries that Britain dealt with never fully
appreciated what they were up against. When the so-called Anglo-Persian Oil
Company was formed, the government of Iran had no idea that the company they
were dealing with was wholly owned by the British government. Even Royal Dutch
Petroleum was a British operation, even though they maintained the fiction of a
corporate hdqrs in Holland and employed mostly Dutch workers and management.
OIL
COMES ON THE SCENE
In
the 1890s, a navy captain named Fischer released a study comparing the
strategic advantage of oil-powered warships to coal-powered. The data showed that in any war fought
between coal-powered and oil-powered ships, the coal-powered warships would always lose. A steamship with an
oil-fired boiler would have only slightly higher speed. But it would have twice
the range. It would also produce
little or no smoke, whereas a coal burner would have a plume visible for forty
miles. A coal burner took
two days to re-fuel vs. two hours for an oil burner. And when firing up a cold boiler, a coal burner took 11 hours
to come up to full steam, and took four hours to get enough steam just to move
the ship. An oil burner could be
at full steam in four hours, and could have enough steam to move the ship in 30
minutes. This was not good news for England--which, as Churchill said, was “an
island made of coal”---but had no oil.
In
1904 Captain Fischer had become First Admiral Lord Fischer, and he began
converting England’s fleet to oil. He also convened a committee to study how
England might obtain that oil.
Since that moment, oil has been a strategic material. From that time, British policy has
focused on not only obtaining oil, but denying it to any potential competitor
wherever possible. As early as 1892, Lord Curzon, later viceroy of India, had
written that. “The concession of a port on the Persian Gulf to Russia would be
a provocation to war.”
In
1905, acting through a covert agent, Britain obtained a franchise on the development
of Iranian oil
from an engineer named D’Arcy. This franchise had been granted to D’Arcy in
1901 by the Shah. It happened that
D’Arcy was a pious Christian. So the British agent, disguised as a priest,
convinced D’Arcy that the new Anglo-Persian Oil Company was a private company
run by good conscientious Christians.
IRAQI
OIL, AND THE GERMANS:
In
1889 some German businessmen formed a plan to build a railway from Berlin to Constantinople.
By 1896 1,000 km had been built, and the Turkish government had agreed to allow
the line to continue to Baghdad, with plans to extend it eventually to Kuwait
and the Persian Gulf. Such a line
would open to Germany a vast West Asian interior market. It would also allow
German goods a short cut to India, one that did not need the Suez Canal. The
British bankers, who were already extremely concerned about Germany, now became
nearly apoplectic. There was only room for one great trading power. If Germany
was in, Britain would be out.
But the last straw was when Germany was awarded the full mineral rights to a 20
km corridor on either side of the proposed railway, right through Mosul, which
is now at the heart of the Iraqi oil region. Over the next 15 years, Britain
did everything possible to stall or prevent the construction of this railway.
BALKAN WARS
BALKAN WARS
The route would have to go through
Germany, Austro-Hungary, Serbia, Bulgaria, and Turkey. One obvious thing that
might obstruct the project would be any kind of destabilizing little war in the
Balkans. Conveniently for the British, in the decade leading up to 1914, a
series of such wars just happened to occur: first the Bulgarian war and then the Turkish war.
Another device for delaying the project
was for England to pretend to be interested in jointly financing the project,
then canceling at the last minute. The Germans had continually begged Britain
to join in the endeavor, as it would be extremely expensive to finance alone.
Finally, in 1913, they realized that the British had no good faith intent of
ever financing the project, so a bill was introduced in the Reichstag to have
the German government fully fund the Berlin to Baghdad Railway. This was the
bill being debated when war broke out in 1914.
THE FINAL SOLUTION
Obviously,
the causes of the First World War are complex. And some historians argue that the outbreak of war was
simply a mistake--a series of unfortunate diplomatic blunders. But Engdahl claims that a full decade
before the war, British government leaders had already concluded that English
trade dominance could not be preserved much longer unless a way could be found
to wreck the German economy, and that this would probably require a war. The
secret three-way alliance between Britain, Russia, and France was in no way a
defensive strategy. If you
wanted a defensive pact, it would make no sense to keep it a secret. Instead,
it was more like a mouse trap. If
any one ally was attacked, it would spring the trap. The idea was to trick
Germany into a war that she couldn’t possibly win, and which would cripple her
economy, and then impose post-war conditions that would keep it crippled
forever. Would the British
really start a war that would kill 20 million people just to maintain trade
supremacy? Well, they probably
didn’t know it would kill 20 million people. They probably thought it would be
one of those minor European wars that no one even remembers. With a tiny
country like Germany up against Russia, France, and Britain, how could the war
possibly last more than a few months? There were many factors that convinced British bankers that
the German economy would have to be destroyed if Britain were to survive. The
fact that German industry and shipping would soon eclipse Britain was one
factor. And the fact that the Germans were building a huge navy to protect
their shipping was another. And
the Berlin to Baghdad Rail route, with a German short cut to the Far East, was
perhaps the main factor. According to Engdahl, even with that, the peace might
have been saved. But when the rail corridor included access to Iraqi oil--that
was it. The battle lines were drawn.
Once
the war started, Britain pulled most of its troops out of the front lines in
France and seized the Arabian Peninsula.
They told the Arabs that they were liberating them from the Ottoman
Empire. But a secret agreement, the Sykes-Picot accord, had carved up the whole
Middle East between Britain, France, and Russia, with Britain getting most of
the oil. After the Bolshevik revolution, the Leninist government in 1917 found
a copy of this accord and made it public. The Arabs realized they’d been duped.
T.E. Lawrence was aware of the
fraud, and he wasn’t happy about it. But he felt if it was a choice between betraying the Arabs
and losing the war, he’d rather win the war. The French were outraged that the British would leave them
to fight the western front mostly alone, but they could do little but accept
it. And when the war was over,
Britain already had troops on the ground over the whole Middle East, so the
French accepted whatever crumbs the British chose to leave them.
After
the war, The British and French insisted on imposing crushing reparations
payments, which was the final blow to a German economy already weakened by war.
Wilson had objected, arguing that the German economy could never be rebuilt
under such a heavy burden. Most of us have been taught that it was out of
French and British ignorance that these reparations were imposed--that the
incompetent French and British politicians simply did not understand what they
were doing. Engdahl says they knew exactly what they were doing--crushing
Germany! That had been the whole purpose of the war----to destroy the German economy.
How
did the U.S. come to intervene?
American banks, through J. P. Morgan, had loaned tens of billions of
dollars to Britain to finance the war. If Britain lost, these loans would never
be repaid and all large American banks would become insolvent. And such a bank failure would have taken
down the entire American economy, along with the economy of the entire world.
Engdahl goes on to explain:
- Why the British
bankers originally backed Hitler.
- How Britain made “debt
vassals” of third world countries, as a way of controlling them, and why
Kissinger used the same strategy, though it nearly wrecked the U.S.
economy.
- Why British banks
backed the establishment of the state of Israel
- Why the U.S. set up
conditions to start a war in Kosovo, and sent the Army in to stop it.
- Which former Soviet
states now have U.S. air bases---and which of these states have oil.
- Which political and
corporate leaders were probably assassinated by British MI5 units.
Tuesday, September 11, 2012
A Keynesian Error
A Keynesian Error, (and Why Unions are Still Needed. )
When most people think of Keynesian economics, they think of deliberate deficit spending used to stimulate a sluggish economy and prevent the country from sliding into a recession. That was indeed a part of the theory of John Maynard Keynes. Another part was deliberately running a surplus to slow down an overheated economy and prevent runaway inflation. When a country runs a surplus, it removes money from the economy through taxation faster than it injects money into the economy through government spending. Running a fiscal deficit does the opposite.
When most people think of Keynesian economics, they think of deliberate deficit spending used to stimulate a sluggish economy and prevent the country from sliding into a recession. That was indeed a part of the theory of John Maynard Keynes. Another part was deliberately running a surplus to slow down an overheated economy and prevent runaway inflation. When a country runs a surplus, it removes money from the economy through taxation faster than it injects money into the economy through government spending. Running a fiscal deficit does the opposite.
According
to Keynes, at any point in time, there should be exactly enough money
circulating in the economy to purchase all of the goods which is produced. If this situation does not occur
naturally, then Keynes believed that it is the obligation of government to
create such a situation, because if government does not do this—then no one
will do it. And any deficiency in
circulating cash will result in some of the goods being unsold. As unsold goods accumulates, this leads
to layoffs and eventually a depression.
But if there is too much cash, that is, too many dollars chasing too few
goods, the result will be increasing prices, and eventually runaway
inflation. Yet,
at some point in between, there must exist a fiscal policy which would be
neutral. To most people, It seems
natural to assume that this point would occur when the budget is balanced. Originally, even Keynes assumed this. But this would be a serious error. The stable, neutral point does not seem
to occur with the budget in balance--it occurs with a slight deficit. But
why? For years, I have struggled
to find an answer. I think I now have one.
The first answer I saw was related to population increase. A neutral economy might keep everyone working if the number of workers remained constant. But if the number of young people entering the workforce were to exceed the number of old workers retiring, then some expansion of the economy would be required so that the increase in the total number of workers did not radically exceed the number of jobs. So an expansionary fiscal policy, at least a slight one, might always be required.
The first answer I saw was related to population increase. A neutral economy might keep everyone working if the number of workers remained constant. But if the number of young people entering the workforce were to exceed the number of old workers retiring, then some expansion of the economy would be required so that the increase in the total number of workers did not radically exceed the number of jobs. So an expansionary fiscal policy, at least a slight one, might always be required.
You
may point out that our population is not expanding much anymore, so this
argument has little to say about today, even though it may explain the need for
expansion in the 50s and 60s. But there are ways that an economy can
be swamped with new workers without any population expansion at all. During the 50s, most married women were
“stay at home” housewives. But
between 1965 and 1980, millions sought work outside the home. The increase in female workforce
participation in the U.S. in this time period amounted to about 19 million
women. This deluge of excess
labor in itself could have caused a severe depression, but since the Johnson
administration tried to fight the Viet Nam War without raising taxes to pay for
it, we had a wildly expansionary fiscal policy, and so we had runaway inflation
instead.
But
today, the number of women working outside the home is probably as high as it’s
likely to get, so why is the expansion still needed? Well, it’s like this: Just when the supply of labor and the demand for labor is in
perfect balance, some no good bastard, (like me) will install a piece of labor
saving machinery, which will cause layoffs in that industry.
Mind you, the specific company where the
layoffs will occur will probably not be the firm where the labor saving equipment
was installed. More likely, the
firm with the new equipment will lower its labor cost enough to expand its
share of the market, and layoffs or plant closings will occur at the firm of a
competitor who could not afford to buy such equipment. But for the industry as a whole, more
labor saving equipment equals fewer workers, unless total demand increases.
And what increases total demand?
An expansionary fiscal policy, of course!
So
what is the exact relationship between increased labor productivity, and the
deficit required to keep the country out of severe depression? It depends. What it depends on is the strength of labor unions. During the 40s, 50s, and 60s, we
had rapid increases in productivity, but we also had tough, effective
unions. So whenever a firm
installed equipment which decreased the hours required for a unit of
production, the unions demanded, and usually got, a raise in hourly wage. They were simply demanding that some of
the benefit of the increased productivity per worker be shared with the workers
who made it possible. Because the
average wage per hour increased as the hours per unit of production decreased,
there was little or no net depressive effect on aggregate demand. Put another way, if the workers in the
firm with the new equipment were paid a high enough increase in wages, this
would help compensate for the reductions in national buying power caused by the
layoffs from the firm which closed its doors. In fact, this increase in
spending power given to workers as a group could cause the economy as a whole to expand enough to provide
jobs for all of the workers who were squeezed out. So only a very modest deficit was required to keep the
economy humming along.
But
today, industrial unions do not usually have the power to force corporations to
share the benefits of productivity increases with workers. So those workers who are squeezed out
will not be rescued by the boom caused by the increased buying power of other
workers. Either the boom to provide
the required jobs will be produced by substantial deficit spending, or else we will
have a depression. I know there
are many conservatives who do not much care for big unions--or for big deficits either. And they will not be happy to learn
that, over the long run, they may have to choose one or the other. But
remember, when you have a real depression, it isn’t just workers who go broke.
Wednesday, September 5, 2012
The Car Sales Boom of 2015
According
to an article in the Aug 5, 2012 issue of The New York Times Magazine,
auto makers are betting that 2015 will be an all time record sales year. According to Adam Davidson’s article, 2015 IS GONNA BE THE YEAR, Volkswagen just opened a new plant in
Chattanooga, Honda is expanding production in Indiana, Kia in Georgia, and
Hyundai in Alabama. Why do they
think a boom is coming? Do they suspect that we will all be rolling in money
then? No, they just think that
income and consumer confidence are slowly improving and will continue to
improve. But mainly, they think
that most of the current fleet of American cars will be un-repairable by 2015. Today, the average American car
is 11 years old. That’s an all
time record. And if 11 years is the average age, then millions of cars
must be much, much older than 11 years--and sooner or later, all things
die.
Right
now, there is enough cash and unused credit in the economy to support a much
higher level of consumer spending than we are seeing. While 10% of the work force is still unemployed and another
10% is underemployed, we can assume that 80% are still earning a paycheck--but
aren’t spending much of it. For
the last three years, they have been paying down their credit card debt, making
payments on their houses (so that they now have equity), and some of them are
saving cash. Most of them now have
good enough credit so that they could drive home a new car at any time—but they
are too scared to do it. But when
their old junker finally dies, they will certainly have to buy something. So, can’t they just buy another old car? From whom? This time, when your old junker bites
the dust, most of the other old cars will be ready to junk too.
For
those who would never consider buying a brand new vehicle, the demand in
2015 will be for used, low mileage cars. In order to fill that future demand,
auto makers are now offering attractive rental deals, figuring that in three
years, there will be a strong market for the rentals being returned at that
time.
To
me, the really amazing thing is that the average American car has been on the
road for 11 years. In the 1950s,
people who bought new cars traded every two or three years. Those who bought
used cars bought these trade-ins and kept them for another two or three years. When
I got out of high school in 1957 and got my first job, I immediately bought my
first car. It was a 1950 Plymouth
Business Coupe. It was 7 years
old, had 40,000 miles on the clock, and the body was in flawless
condition. I paid $160 for
it. A dollar then was worth
a lot more than a dollar today, but that still wasn’t a lot of money. It was about two weeks pay. I remember marveling that it was
possible to buy a car that still looked and drove like a new car--for only two
weeks pay. Someone replied, “Yes,
but who would want to be seen driving a 7 year old car?”
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)